Three line summary
-
Conditional expectations exist in a natural way for simple functions, by taking extensions they also exist for integrable functions to a Banach space $L^1(\Omega\to E)$.
-
Using conditional expectations we can define what a martingale is just like in the real case.
-
The space of continuous $p$-integrable martingales is a Banach space.
Why should I care?
Banach valued martingales form the basis of SPDEs. This is because analogously to Itô integration of real-valued processes. Integrating against a Wiener process valued in a Banach space the same will produce a square-integrable continuous martingale.
1. Conditional expectation
In graduate-level probability courses, given a $\sigma-$algebra $\mathcal{G}$ one shows that by applying Radon-Nikodyn’s theorem, for any real-valued random variable $X\in L^1(\Omega\to R)$ there exists a conditional expectation $\mathbb{E}\U {\mathcal{G}}\zl X\zr $ verifying that
Of course, now that we have created an integral for the space of random variables $L^1(\Omega\to E)$ to some Banach space $E$, we would like to see whether such a conditional expectation also exists for these functions. To start with, if we are given a simple function
It is a simple calculation to show that
verifies the desired formula (we note that, since $1\U {A\U k}$ are real-valued, so $\mathbb{E}\U {\mathcal{G}}\zl 1\U {A\U k}\zr $ are well defined). Furthermore, we have that $\mathbb{E}\U \mathcal{G}$ is a linear, and pointwise continuous operator with
This allows us to show the following
Theorem 1 (Existence and uniqueness of conditional expectation). Let $X\in L^1(\Omega\to E)$ for some Banach space $E$. Then $X$ has a conditional expectation satisfying
Proof. We have already proved the above inequality for simple processes. By the previous post, 1 we can take $X\U n$ converging to $X$ in $L^1(\Omega\to E)$ to obtain that
As a result, $\mathbb{E}\U {\mathcal{G}}\zl X\U n\zr $ is a Cauchy sequence in the complete space $L^1(\Omega\to E)$, and so converges to some function $Z$. Now passing to the limit in the defining equation for the conditional expectation shows that $Z=\mathbb{E}\U \mathcal{G}\zl X\zr $. Finally, to prove uniqueness we have that if both $Z\U 1, Z\U 2$ satisfy
Then using the linearity of the Bochner integral we obtain that $w(Z\U 1)=w(Z\U 2)$ for all linear function $w$, so $Z\U 1=Z\U 2$. ◻
In proofs it is often useful to reduce infinite dimensional conditional expectations to finite dimensional ones. This can be done with the following trick
Proposition 1 (Linearity of the conditional expectation). Let $X\in L^1(\Omega\to E)$ for some Banach space $E$. Then it holds that
Proof. This follows from the definition of conditional expectation and the linearity of the Bochner integral. ◻
2. Martingales
Okay, so we leveraged some inequalities to prove the existence of a conditional expectation. This done, the following definition, which mimics the real case, is quite natural.
Definition 1. Let $\{M(t)\}\U {t\in I}$, be a stochastic process on $(\Omega, \mathcal{F}, \mathbb{P})$ with a filtration $\{\mathcal{F}\U {t}\}\U {t \in I}$. The process $M$ is called an $\mathcal{F}\U {t}$-martingale, if:
-
$M(t)\in L^1(\Omega\to E)$ for all $t\in I$
-
$M(t):\mathcal{F}\U {t} \to \mathcal{B}(E)$ for all $t\in I$,
-
$\mathbb{E}\U {\mathcal{F}\U {s}}\left[ M(t)\right] =M(s)$ for all $s \leq t$.
The concept of submartingale (supermartingale) is defined by replacing the equality in 3. with a $\geq$ (with a $\leq$). In the real case, the absolute value of a martingale is a submartingale. To obtain this result for Banach valued Martingales we need to assume that $E$ is separable so that we can use the following result.
Lemma 1 Let $E$ be a separable metric space, then there exists a countable family of linear functions $\ell \U n \in E^\star $ such that
Proof. Let $e\U n$ be a countable dense subset of $E$. By Hahn Banach’s theorem we may take $\ell\U n$ such that
By density, we may take a sequence $e\U {n\U k} \to e$. This gives,
Taking limits we conclude that
Since the reverse inequality holds by definition of the norm on $E^\star$ this concludes the proof. ◻
The crucial part of requiring $E$ to be separable is that the norm is a countable supremum of linear functions. We recall that it is the only countable supremum of measurable functions that are measurable. Let us abbreviate $\mathbb{E}\U {\mathcal{F}\U t}$ by $\mathbb{E}\U t$. Then, as in the real case, we have the following.
Lemma 2 Let $M(t)$ be a martingale valued in a separable metric space $E$ , then $\norm{M(t)}$ is a submartingale.
Proof. Let us take $\ell\U n$ as in Lemma 1. Then, since $M$ is a martingale, by the linearity of conditional expectation (Proposition 1) and by Fatou’s lemma for the limsup
◻
Let us recall the following result for real-valued martingales
Lemma 3 (Doob’s maximal martingale inequality). Let $\{X\U k\}\U {k=1}^\infty$ be a real-valued sub-martingale. Then it holds that
As a consequence, if $X\U t,t\in\zl 0,T\zr $ is left (or right) continuous then
The idea of the above result is that since $X\U k$ is a submartingale, $X\U k\lesssim X\U {k+1}\lesssim…\lesssim X\U n$. Getting from the continuous to the discrete case is possible by using the continuity of $X$ and approximating it on some finer and finer mesh $t\U 0,…,t\U n$. For all the details see page $5$ of 2.
This said, applying Doob’s maximal martingale inequality together with the Lemma $1$ gives that
Theorem 2 (Doob’s maximal inequality). Let $p>1$ and let $E$ be a separable Banach space. If $M(t)\in L^p (\Omega \to E)$, is a right-continuous $E$-valued $\mathcal{F}\U {t}$-martingale, then
Proof. This follows by using that $\norm{M(t)}$ is a real valued sub-martingale and Doob’s maximal inequality. ◻
Doob’s inequality is essentially an equality between different function norms we can place on the space of continuous Martingales and will provide a very powerful tool later on. We state this precisely below.
Corollary 1. Let $M$ be a (left or right) continuous martingale to a separable Banach space $E$. Then the following are equivalent
-
$M\in L^\infty(\zl 0,T\zr \to L^2(\Omega\to E))$.
-
$M\in \hat{L}^2(\Omega\to L^\infty(\zl 0,T\zr \to E))$.
-
$\mathbb{E}\zl \norm{M(T)}^2\zr <\infty$.
Where we recall from the previous post that $\hat{L}^p$ symbolizes that $M$ may not be separately valued and only have an integrable norm. That said, the same reasoning shows that the above result also holds for the integrable $L^p$ spaces.
A useful space of Martingales is as follows
Definition 2. Let $M(t)$ be a $E$ valued martingale with index set $I=\zl 0,T\zr $, then we define
and give it the norm
By Theorem $2$ we have that
And that any of the norms of these spaces is equivalent to the one set on $\mathcal{M}\U T^2(E)$. This is useful in the following result
Proposition 1. Let $E$ be a separable Banach (Hilbert) space, then $\mathcal{M}\U T^2(E)$ is a Banach (Hilbert) space.
Proof. Let us first consider the case when $E$ is a Banach space. By the previous observation and the completeness of the $\hat{L}^p$ spaces proved in the previous post, $\mathcal{M}\U T^2(E)$ is a subspace of a Hilbert space. As a result, it is sufficient to show that it is closed. Let $M\U n$ converge to $M \in \hat{L}^2(\Omega\to L^\infty(\zl 0,T\zr \to E))$. Then, by the equivalence of the norms, we have that $M\U n(t)\to M(t)\in L^1(\Omega\to E)\subset L^2(\Omega\to E)$ so that for all $A\in\mathcal{F}\U s$
This shows that $M$ is a martingale. Furthermore, as was seen in Proposition 2 of the previous post 1
Since $M\U {n\U k}(\cdot,\omega)$ are continuous and continuity is preserved by uniform limits this proves that $M$ is continuous almost everywhere. In consequence, $\mathcal{M}\U T^2(E)$ is closed and thus a Banach space. In the case where $E$ is a Hilbert space we can endow $\mathcal{M}\U T^2(E)$ with the inner product
This concludes the proof. ◻
In future installments, we will prove that a Banach valued Wiener process with trace class covariance belongs to this space and use it to define the stochastic integral that leads to the construction of SPDEs.